The concept of locally-relevant medical training was first
introduced by
Eyal
and Hurst as a way to combat “brain drain,” the exodus of trained
professionals from poor sending countries to the richer countries of the West.
Brain drain can have devastating consequences for the already fragile health
systems of underdeveloped sending countries, and it represents a massive loss
of investment for sending countries who have subsidized their graduates’
medical training only to see them leave to provide their services abroad. The
WHO
has since endorsed the locally-relevant training model as a way in which to
address the disproportionate shortage of health professionals in poor and
remote regions of the world. So, how does it work? Locally-relevant medical
training is designed to make foreign medical graduates, 1) less desirable to
Western hirers and, 2) better equipped to practice medicine in the scarcity
conditions of their home countries. What this means is that medical students in
sending countries would no longer be trained to score well on US board
examinations or how to read MRI scans, but rather how to manage local endemic
disease and succeed with the diagnostic equipment and supplies available in
their localities.
The idea of locally-relevant training sounds practical, and it
may indeed be an effective way to avoid the pitfalls of brain drain if
correctly instituted. Indeed, if the paramount goal is to increase and/or
introduce healthcare services into underserved regions of the world, locally-relevant
training appears to be a commonsense solution. But, some may argue that it is
not necessarily the answer. First, is the locally-relevant model fair to
its students? They are taught “second-rate” medicine as compared to the Western
gold standard. As a result, their freedom of movement is restricted as they are
no longer qualified to practice medicine in the West. Is it okay to deny these
individuals the opportunity to study the latest and greatest advances in
medicine simply because of where they live? Second, it can also be argued that
sending countries should provide more incentive for their graduates to remain
at home. This may entail increasing wages, improving practice conditions, and
expanding research opportunities.
Does a focus on locally-relevant medical training unfairly
place the impetus on sending countries to change the status quo? After all, blame
for the phenomenon of brain drain does not fall squarely on the sending
countries; it is in large part driven by a shortage of medical professionals in
the West, the “pull” factors attracting foreign graduates to the West, and,
surely, “push” factors that drive foreign graduates from practicing at home. Some
may argue that the richer countries should implement policies on their end to
protect sending countries from the harmful effects of brain drain. The West,
however, is the beneficiary of the status quo; why would it “shoot itself in
the foot” and preempt a scheme that is an easy fix for its own physician
shortage problems? To be fair, there are initiatives like
PEPFAR’s
Medical Education Partnership Initiative that work to increase the local
retention of health care professionals in sub-Saharan Africa and other regions
of the world. But this initiative and many others do not address the real
problem: there are too few medical professionals graduating each year from
Western institutions to provide adequate care for its population. Countries in
the West should train more homegrown medical professionals to cover their own
deficits if they are serious about mitigating the deleterious effects of brain
drain on sending countries.
Guest post by David Kennedy, Medical Student
University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill
Labels: brain drain, developing world, medical education